THE WILLIAM DAVIDSON INSTITUTE AT THE UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN
The MNC as an Agent of Change for Host-Country
Institutions: FDI and Corruption
By: Chuck Kwok & Solomon Tadesse
William Davidson Institute Working Paper Number 882 September 2006
The MNC as an Agent of Change for Host-Country Institutions: FDI and Corruption
Chuck Kwok + and Solomon Tadesse ++
This version: Sept. 2006
Abstract Most empirical research examines how the institutional environment of corruption shapes the behavior of MNCs. In this study, we would like to highlight the other side of the picture: how the presence of MNC may shape the institutional environment of corruption over time. We propose three avenues through which the MNC may have an impact on its host institutions: the regulatory pressure effect, the demonstration effect, and the professionalization effect. Based on extensive data on FDI and corruption for a large sample of countries over the last 30 years, the empirical results are consistent with our general hypothesis that foreign direct investment generates positive spillover effects on the institutional environment of host countries. Such findings provide a glimmer of hope for the future of the host country where corruption is most prevalent. Key Words: Foreign Direct Investment, Corruption JEL Codes: F21, F23, M14, M16, O73 + Moore School of Business, University of South Carolina, Columbia, SC 29208. E-mail: [email protected]. ++ Corresponding author. Stephen M. Ross School of Business, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI 48109. E-mail: [email protected]. The authors would like to thank participants and the editors of the JIBS Special Issue on the “Three Lens” conference for comments and valuable suggestions.
1
Introduction
With the expansion of international business activities, the study of corruption and its effects has
received increased attention recently. Multinational corporations (MNCs) are careful in choosing host
countries for their foreign subsidiaries, as they are concerned that pervasive corruption could increase
their operational costs and risks. So are also multinational banks, since corruption could drain the
investment funds of a country, hampering its economic growth and debt service capacity. International
development agencies are concerned that financial aids meant to help economic development and the
poor may be squandered by corrupt government officials.
Following Macrae (1982), in this study, we define corruption as an arrangement that involves an
exchange between two parties (the “demander” and the “supplier”) which i) has an influence on the
allocation of resources either immediately or in the future; and ii) involves the use or abuse of public or
collective responsibility for private ends. The harmful effects of corruption have been extensively
documented in the literature (see, e.g., Mauro (1995, 1997), and Rose-Ackerman (1975)). Corrupt
payments amount to a significant percentage of gross national product, since the rents extracted by a
corrupt system gets built into the cost structure of organizations. Corruption distorts efficient resource
allocation. Corruption rewards unproductive behavior by channeling unmerited contracts and rights to
companies in exchange for bribes, at the expense of efficient and innovative firms. The toleration of
corruption in some areas of public life can facilitate a downward spiral in which the malfeasance of some
encourages more and more people to engage in corruption over time. Pervasive corruption undermines
the legitimacy of governments. Corruption in the provision of public goods and services in the imposition
of costs casts a cloud over governments seeking popular legitimacy (Rose-Ackerman (1999)).
Most empirical work regarding corruption assumes the context where the institutional setting
shapes the behavior of the MNC. We certainly recognize that, in order to strive for external legitimacy,
the MNC needs to adapt to its institutional context (Glynn and Abzug (2002)). However, in this study, we
would like to point out the other side of the picture: how the presence of MNCs could shape the
2
institutional environment of corruption over time. We propose three avenues through which the MNC
may have an impact on its host institutions: regulatory pressure effect, demonstration effect, and
professionalization effect.
The balance of the paper is organized into five sections. Following the introduction, the second
section II reviews the literature on corruption. The third section III explores how the MNC interacts with
its host environment and formulates the research hypotheses. In the fourth section, we describe the data
and methodology used in the paper. Section V reports the empirical results. Finally, section VI
concludes the paper and discusses the implications of our findings.
II. Literature review
As a topic of key concern, the study of corruption has generated numerous published scholarly
studies. In the academic literature, there are two main streams of studies on the subject. The first stream
employs the approach of mathematical modeling to analyze the causes, effects and various conditions
related to corruption. For examples, Rose-Ackerman (1975) examines the relationship between market
structures and the incidence of corrupt dealings in the government contracting process. She then discusses
how revising contracting procedures and reorganizing market structures can reduce criminal incentives of
corruption. Shleifer and Vishny (1993) contend that weak governments that do not control their agencies
experience high corruption levels. Moreover, the illegality of corruption and the need for secrecy make it
much more distortionary and costly than taxation.
The second research stream consists of various empirical studies. This line of research is
facilitated by the publication of worldwide corruption indices by agencies such as the Transparency
International, World Bank, Economist Intelligence Unit and so forth. The corruption indices can be used
either as an independent or dependent variable. For instance, using corruption as an independent variable,
studies have found that corruption contributes to suboptimal economic growth (Barro (1996)), poor
economic competitiveness (Ades and di Tella (1999)), less investment and inefficient government (Knack
3
and Keefer (1995); Mauro (1997)), and a decrease in the level of trust or social capital by citizens (La
Porta et al. (1997); Knack and Keefer (1997)).
Using the corruption index as the dependent variable, Husted (1999) finds that corruption is
significantly associated with GNP per capita and related to the cultural variables power distance,
masculinity and uncertainty avoidance. Robertson and Watson (2004) find that in the short run, the more
rapid the rate of change of foreign direct investment (FDI), the higher level of corruption.
III. MNCs and corruption in host countries
MNC as an organization shaped by the host institution
Empirical studies have been conducted to show how a host country’s corruption significantly
reduces its inflows of foreign direct investment (Lambsdorff (1999); Mauro (1995); Wei (1997)). Besides
the volume of FDI inflows, Rodriguez, Uhlenbruck and Eden (2005) contend that the type of corruption
in the host country would also affect the choice of entry modes. Using the institutional framework, they
introduce a two-dimensional framework of corruption: pervasiveness and arbitrariness. They argue that
the higher the pervasiveness of corruption, the higher is the likelihood that an MNC will choose to enter
via a wholly owned subsidiary rather than a local partner.
Most of the studies mentioned above examine how the institutional environment of corruption
may shape the behavior of MNCs. We certainly recognize that in order to strive for external legitimacy,
the MNC needs to adapt to its institutional context (Glynn and Abzug (2002)). However, in this study, we
would like to highlight the other side of the picture: how the presence of MNC may shape the institutional
environment of corruption over time. We contend that the MNC is not just a passive subject; it may also
serve an agent of change.
4
MNC as an agent of change to the host institution
Using the framework of the institutionalization theory, Westney (1993) discusses the potential
significant impacts of MNCs on the organizational patterns within a country. MNC subsidiaries in some
countries can play a major role in establishing building blocks of organizations. The introduction of new
modes of business practice in MNC subsidiaries can challenge the legitimacy of existing patterns and
stimulate debates on better business practice in the host country. The mirror image of this influence is the
“de-institutionalization” of local firms’ existing organizational patterns. Similarly, Dacin, Ventresca and
Beal (1999) review research on organizations to highlight prevailing and emerging conceptions on
embeddedness. They briefly discuss the concept of “disembeddedness”. They argue that globalization
may be regarded as a disembedding process that strips individuals and firms from their local structures
and allows for restructuring at a more global level.
Following this perspective, we contend that the presence of foreign-owned subsidiaries will, on
the average, reduce the level of corruption of the host country. We propose that the MNC influences its
institutional environment over time via three major effects: regulatory pressure effect, demonstration
effect, and professionalization effect.1 For better explanation, our main ideas are illustrated in Figure 1.
This diagram conveys as a general framework on how the MNC may serve as an agent of change for
host-country institutions.
Within the host country environment, local governments and the business community influence
the behavior of foreign-owned subsidiaries. In Figure 1, we use a thick arrow line to represent such
influence, indicating that such influence tends to be strong and immediate. However, we argue that there
is a milder force of influence flowing back from the MNC to the host government and business
1 We benefited much from the insights of DiMaggio and Powell (1983) who discuss institutional isomorphism.
Isomorphism is a constraining process that forces one unit in a population to resemble other units that face the similar set of environmental conditions. Our proposed three effects correspond with their three mechanisms of isomorphism: coercive isomorphism; mimetic isomorphism; and normative isomorphism. However, the focus of DiMaggio and Powell is on isomorphism. In order not to confuse readers who are familiar with the institutional theory, we use three other terms to represent the effects through which the MNC may shape the host country institution over time.
5
community. We use a thin arrow line to represent such influence as it is mild, subtle and takes long time
to realize. Besides conforming to the local business practice to gain legitimacy, MNCs are also
accountable to and constrained by their home-country environment and the international business
community at large. Through the regulatory pressure, demonstration, and professionalization effects,
MNCs gradually shape the host-country institutions. One motivating factor for the host institutions to
change is that the host country also wants to gain legitimacy within the bigger, global business
environment. As the host country grows, it would like to enhance its international reputation and attracts
more business. Under this general framework of how MNCs may shape host-country institutions over
time, we study the specific relationship between FDI and host-country corruption.
Regulatory pressure effect
In a business culture where corruption is pervasive, corruption becomes the modality of business
practice in local businesses and government offices. It becomes part of the regular practice and both
parties of the transaction would take it for granted. However, when a government official deals with a
foreign entity, he or she may not be able to conduct business as usual. The business people representing
the MNCs may be reluctant in offering a bribe. Firstly, the subsidiary of an MNC is faced with two sets
of isomorphic pressures — the MNC’s and the host country’s (Davis et al. (2000); Kostova and Roth
(2002)). Besides trying to gain external legitimacy by adopting the common corrupt business practice of
the host country, it also has to strive for internal legitimacy as the headquarter in the home-country
environment may have adopted norms and practices that ban corrupt behaviors by their subsidiaries.
Secondly, there is the regulatory pressure from the home government and the international
business community (DiMaggio and Powell (1983), Oliver (1997)). For instance, the U.S. Foreign
Corrupt Practices Act, enacted in 1977, was prompted by a series of scandals involving questionable
payments by U.S. firms to overseas government officials. This act prohibits U.S. firms from giving
anything of value (such as a payment, gift or bribe) to induce a foreign government to enter into a
contract or business advantage or relationship. This act carries criminal penalties, imprisonment for up to
five years, fines of up to $100,000 for individuals, and fines up to $2 million for companies.
6
Similar legislation is enacted in the global business community. On November 21, 1997,
representatives from 33 countries signed the Convention on Combating Bribery of Foreign Public
Officials in International Business Transactions. Among them were 28 of the 29 member states of the
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), together with Argentina, Brazil,
Bulgaria, Chile, and the Solvak Republic (Doh et al., 2003).
Under regulatory pressure from home country and the international business community, the
employees of MNC’s subsidiaries are reluctant to offer bribes. If the MNC has enough bargaining power
and its presence is much desired by the host government, it may simply refuse offering bribes. Even if the
subsidiary employees think that they need to engage in bribery in order to secure business, the local
officials may need to think of some circuitous ways to accept the bribes so that the MNC employees are
less likely to get caught. Facing a foreign business party, the local government officials are constrained
somewhat in their bribery acts. It cannot be just business as usual.
Demonstration effect
In the international business literature, there is a line of research that studies spillover effects of
foreign direct investment (Globerman (1979), Haddad and Harrison (1993), Eden et al. (1997), Aitken
and Harrison (1999), and Liu et al. (2000)). The discussion of the spillover effects concentrates mainly on
productivity and technological transfer. For instance, Blomström and Kokko (1998) and Gorg and Strobl
(2001) summarize how FDI may affect the productivity of domestic firms. First, competition from FDI
may force domestic firms to update production technology and change management styles in order to
maintain their competitiveness. Second, domestic firms may learn from observing the MNCs’ practice
when there are close relationships between them. Thirdly, MNCs train their employees who may later
move to domestic firms with learnt skills.
Following this line of thought, we argue that there may also be a spillover or demonstration effect
on corruption (Oliver (1997)). In some host countries, corruption has been immersed deep in the local
business culture. Local business people and government officials may think that this is the “normal” way
to get business done. However, when they deal with the MNCs through negotiations, joint ventures,
7
upstream or downstream relationships in the business chains, being geographically and operationally
proximate, they have opportunities to observe closely how business decisions and allocations are made
within the MNCs (Eden et al. (1997)). Business can be conducted more efficiently in an environment
built on trust and ethical conduct. In the past, local advocates might also “talk” about ethical business
practice but might not produce a concrete, real example to follow. The presence of MNCs demonstrates
how a cleaner way of conducting business can be more effective and efficient in the long run.
Furthermore, outward-looking local business people and government officials also want to gain
legitimacy within the global business community. They want to enhance the country’s international
reputation and to attract more business. They may model themselves after the MNCs and change their
traditional business practices gradually.
Professionalization effect
DiMaggio and Powell (1983) discuss two important aspects of professionalization. One is the
resting of formal education and of legitimation in a cognitive base produced by university specialists. The
other is the growth and elaboration of professional networks that span organizations and across which
new models diffuse rapidly.
MNCs have been in the forefront of the application of automation, information technology and
managerial techniques in order to enhance business efficiency. Alternatively, academicians strive to
improve business knowledge and develop practical applications by conducting theoretical and empirical
research. All areas of business have, to one degree or another, become sciences. Academic curricula have
become increasingly standardized and professionalized. Business schools around the world tend to adopt
textbooks and course contents from the same pool of leading authors and universities. In order to excel
above their peers, managers want to acquire professional business training. Afraid of being left out by
competitors, even family-owned businesses consider sending their “heirs” to business schools (Ramirez
and Kwok (2006)).
To the younger generation, the MNCs have special appeal. MNCs usually offer substantially
better salaries than domestic companies in host countries. Not only is working for MNCs prestigious, they
8
can be exposed to sophisticated management practices, which will equip them with skills for a successful
business career in the long run. Furthermore, they may be given opportunities to go overseas for short-
term training or business assignments.
To enhance their chance of being recruited by MNCs, the young generation needs to learn about
global business practices. They attend schools to acquire professional business training. To certify their
qualifications, they may take public examinations and join professional associations. Such professional
organizations may set industry-wide ethical codes of conduct, product quality standards, uniform training
or credentialing in occupational professions (Oliver (1997)). Socialized by the professional business
values, they become increasingly critical of the traditional ways. As the “new blood” rise in the corporate
ladder, they become business leaders. They may work for the MNC, they may have started their own
business, or they may have become senior advisors to government officials. They may use their influence
to gradually reform the more corrupt old business practices. In short, the professionalization of the
management practice and the socialization of the younger generation lead to the changes in the host
country institutions over time.
Through the three effects mentioned above, we contend that the presence of MNCs may help
reduce corruption in the host country over time. We put forward the following research hypothesis:
H1: The level of foreign direct investment in a host country is negatively related to its level of corruption over time. 2
However, we need to add quickly that it would be naïve to think that the influence of MNCs on
its environmental institution is always good. There are plenty of anecdotal evidences that MNCs
sometimes bring undesirable influences. In some situations, MNCs exploit natural resources, cause
environmental pollution, employ child labor, or take advantage of the looser regulations of the host
countries (to bypass the stringent regulations and costly requirements of parent countries). In fact,
2 Our hypothesis is on an average effect. First, some MNCs may still engage in corrupt transactions to facilitate
their operation. Second, there are also foreign direct investment flows among developed countries where both the home and host countries do not experience a high level of corruption. In that case, the corruption-reduction effect may be minimal. To examine this latter point, in our robustness tests, we exclude OECD countries from our sample of host countries. The findings are generally robust. Owing to space constraint, the tables of these additional findings are not included in this paper but will be made available to readers upon request.
9
Robertson and Watson (2004) argue that foreign direct investment will lead to an increase of corruption
in the host country in the short run. Firstly, the increase in FDI represents a larger amount of foreign
money flowing into country and, therefore, an expansion of opportunities for bribery. Secondly, the
eagerness of foreign investors to enter the market may tempt host country nationals to resort to corruption
as a means of sharing in the opportunities for profit presented by their own country (Robertson and
Watson (2004)).3 Thirdly, equipped with advanced knowledge in international business and a vast
international network, MNCs may have developed sophisticated skills of bribery. Such practices will
“contaminate” firms in the host country. To represent this opposite view, we put forward the following
alternative hypothesis:
H1a: The level of foreign direct investment in a host country is positively related to its level of corruption over time.
IV. Data and research methodology We attempt to explain the cross-country variations in the extent of corruption based on variations
in the degree of past foreign investment penetration in the economy and other known controls. To that
end, we construct a database composed of three sets of data: (1) measures of corruption in the 2000s (the
dependent variable); (2) measures of MNC presence or foreign direct investment, education, and culture
(the independent variables); and (3) other controls. We have data on these sets of variables for up to 140
countries.
The dependent variable: corruption
Our dependent variable is the extent of corruption in recent years, and is measured by the average
of yearly corruption perception indices over the period 2000 through 2004 obtained from Transparency
International (TI). The TI Corruption Perception Index provides yearly ranking of countries in terms of
the extent of perceived corruption among, primarily, public officials. The index is a composite measure
3 Robertson and Watson (2004) find empirical support for their hypothesis. They use a 1- and 2-year lag-time
between the predictor variable (FDI) and the dependent variable (corruption). Their result reflects more on the short-term effect. On the other hand, the focus of this paper is on the long-term effect of FDI on corruption as the suggested three effects take time to realize.
10
based on polls and surveys of business leaders, residents and country analysts on their experience of
corruption in the respective countries drawn from seven different independent institutions.4 Table 1
reports the summary statistics of the variables while Table 2 shows their correlation coefficients. There is
a wide cross-country variation in the corruption index, ranging from 0.22 in Finland and 0.44 in Denmark
to 8.9 in Bangladesh and 8.66 in Nigeria. Consistent with previous research (e.g., Husted (1999)),
wealthier countries tend to be less corrupt. The corruption perception index is significantly negatively
correlated with log of per capita GDP.
The main independent variable: FDI
We measure the presence of MNCs in a host country by the average net Foreign Direct
Investment (FDI) inflows as a percentage of GDP. We attempt to explain variations in corruption in the
2000s based on the degree of foreign investment penetration in the past. We expect a significant time lag
for the effects to realize but we do not know how far in the past the FDI should be in explaining current
variations in corruption. Nonetheless, we have available data on FDI inflows from 1970 through 1997.
Thus, we consider decade averages of FDI per GDP in the 1970s, the 1980s and the 1990s, as well as an
average over the period 1970 through 1997 respectively. The data on FDI inflows and GDP is obtained
from the World Development Database maintained by the World Bank.
Table 1 provides a summary of the decade averages of FDI to GDP ratios for the sample. The
flow of FDI shows an increasing trend, the average growing from 0.93 percent of GDP in 1970s to 1.089
percent in the 1980s and 2.128 percent in the 90s. In general, high level of FDI appears to be associated
with low corruption in the 2000s. The correlation coefficients between FDI and corruption are mostly
negative and significant (see Table 2).
4 The corruption perception index is a continuous scale variable, taking values from 0 to 10. The higher the value,
the less corrupt the country is. To make the scaling more intuitive, we rescale the corruption perception index by deducting it from 10, so that a 0 on the new scale signifies a corruption-free country and a 10 represents an absolutely corrupt country.
11
V. Empirical findings
FDI and corruption To explore the relations between corruption and the extent of past FDI while controlling for other
potential country factors, we estimate multivariate empirical models. Table 3 presents the main results of
the multivariate regression of corruption on FDI, controlling for a host of control variables. The model is
of the form:
cCin
iiorsss
CC ZFDICORRUPTION ελβα +++= ∑ =
−
119971970,90,80,70* , (1)
where FDI is the FDI inflows as a fraction of GDP, and Z is a set of country-specific control variables
representing the macro-economic, political, legal, religious orientation and institutional environments of
countries that potentially explain the cross-country variations in corruption. FDIC will alternatively take
the values of decade averages of FDI in 1970s, in 1980s, in 1990s and the average FDI to GDP ratio over
1970 through 1997, whereas CORRUPTION will take the average per country of the yearly Corruption
Perception Index averaged over the period 2000 through 2004.
Table 3 clearly shows that past FDI inflows explains a significant portion of the cross-country
variations in corruption. Columns I through IV include the decade averages of FDI to GDP ratios in
combination with the level of GDP per capita as a measure of wealth in the regression. The results show
that the prevalence of corruption today is, on average, lower in countries with larger foreign direct
investment in the past, regardless of how far back we measure the FDI. The coefficients on the key
variables of interest, FDI in 1970s, 1980s, 1990s and 1970 through 1997, are robustly negative and
statistically significant at the one per cent level. The result is broadly consistent with and suggestive of
our hypothesis. Consistent with earlier studies (e.g., Husted (1999) and Mauro (1995)), wealthier
countries have less prevalence of corruption. In general the model works well; in this large sample of 87
to 100 countries, the model explains up to 79 percent of the cross-country variation in the prevalence of
current corruption. To strengthen the veracity of the findings, we control for other variables suggested in
12
the literature, which may also influence a country’s propensity to corruption. We group these controls
into three categories: 1) Education/Human Capital; 2) Political Tradition; and 3) Legal Environments.
Control for education/human capital
The benefits of education as an institution to economic welfare have been well documented.
Education explains cross-country differences in economic growth across countries (see, e.g., Barro
(1991). Education opens up peoples’ eyes to new ways of thinking and practice, and is a source of
increased productivity, efficiency and growth. The development of a critical mass of educated class
would have the potential to change the old ways of life, including corruption. In some way, the effects of
education are similar to those of FDI; much of the benefits are not immediate. To control for the impacts
of education, we include decade averages of secondary school enrollment (as a percentage of eligible
population of the age group) from the World Development database. Columns (V) through (VIII) of
Table 3 show that the effect of educational investment on corruption is similar, though weak, as that of
FDI.
Control for political tradition
The political tradition of the country has a significant impact on its institutional environment.
Governments differ in their role as facilitators of institutional change, and the effect they have on
business practices (see, e.g., Rao et al. (2005)). Autocratic political cultures that lack transparency where
political actors are prone to undermine the rule of law tend to be a breeding ground for abuse of public
office, including corruption. In contrast, open societies with democratic political culture and appropriate
checks and balances in place for constraining actions of political actors are less prone to such abuse. To
control for the effects of political traditions, we use two variables: a measure of the extent of democratic
political system in the country (Jaggers and Marshall (2000)) and a measure of constraints on political
actors in the system (Henisz (2000)). The two variables have significant correlation. To reduce the
possibility of multicollinearity from inclusion of both in the same regression, we orthogonalize the
democracy variable on political constraint and include only the residual value of political constraint.
Columns IX through XII report that the marginal effect of political traditions is not as significant, once
13
one controls for wealth, FDI and education. More democratic countries tend to be less corrupt on
average, though the result is weak and is not sustainable in all specifications.
Control for legal environment
A weak legal system where basic rule of law is lacking would be permissive of abuse of public
office through its failure of legally constraining those in power. In addition, even in the presence of basic
rule of law, the substantive and procedural contents of the law could be a source of variation in the
efficiency of the legal system. Legal systems that are cumbersome in procedural formalism and short of
the legal flexibility that are needed for judicial actions tend to increase the costs of legal proceedings,
prompting the public to seek extra-judicial means of resolution, including corruption. We include the
‘rule of law’ and the ‘legal formalism’ variables developed by Djankov et al. (2003) in our regressions.
Consistent with our conjecture, columns (XIII) through (XV) show that countries with the prevalence of
rule of law tend to be less prone to corruption. Legal systems that are more formal and less flexible
appear to be associated with higher corruption.
As seen in the regression results in Table 3, our main finding that increased past FDI reduced the
prevalence of current corruption is robust to the inclusion of controls for the legal environment, political
tradition, education and economic development.5 The findings are broadly consistent with our main
hypothesis H1 and not supportive of the alternative hypothesis H1a. We argue earlier that the MNC
influences its institutional environment over time via three major effects: regulatory pressure effect,
demonstration effect, and professionalization effect. While it is difficult to provide precise, direct tests of
5 To check for other institutional control variables, instead of the political and legal variables, we also used a
variable that denotes the religious orientation of the country – the percentage of population that follow Protestantism. Religion appears to be a dominant influence on the institutional environment of countries, showing significant correlation with our legal and political variables. Our results are robust to such specification, showing that countries with past FDI exhibit lower rate of corruption, after controlling for religion. The coefficient on FDI is -0.385, significant at 1 percent level. Also countries with dominant protestant influence display lower incidence of corruption. In addition, we considered a much broader measure of institutional development (instead of the political and legal variables we have) from Kaufmann et al. (1999). This measure reflects the institutional quality, based on measures of voice and accountability, political stability and absence of violence, government effectiveness, regulatory burden, law and order, and freedom from graft. The results show robust negative relation between FDI and corruption. The coefficient estimate is -0.139 which is significant at 10 percent level. The results using religious orientation or institutional development as controls are not reported in the tables owing to page constraint. They will be made available to readers upon request.
14
these three effects, we attempt to shed more light on these avenues of influence by examining the
moderating role of past FDI on the known effects of two variables on corruption: Culture and Education.
Culture, education and corruption: the moderating effects of FDI
In this section, we interact the FDI variable with two sets of variables, Culture and Education.
The objectives of this exercise are twofold. First, evidence that FDI presence moderates the negative
effects of culture, or it strengthens the positive effects of education on corruption would be suggestive of
the effects of FDI in play. Second, examining interaction (rather than direct) effects also addresses the
potential endogeneity problem we are cognizant of. In the previous section, we regress corruption in
2000s on lagged values of FDI, the lagged values going as far back as 30 years. The fact that the FDI
values are not contemporaneous with the corruption data minimizes the concerns on reverse causality.
However, it can be argued that past FDI is made in anticipation of the institutional environment in the
future so much so that prediction of low corruption in the future attracts more FDI today. One effective
way of addressing such endogeneity is to focus on the marginal effect of FDI on the effect of a known
variable, such as culture, on corruption. The literature indicates that some cultures, as country effects,
breed in corruption. We find earlier that education as a social investment deters corruption. If we find
that marginally, the known negative effects of culture is moderated and the known positive effects of
education is strengthened by the presence of FDI, then we can say that we have a clearer indicator of
causality running from FDI to corruption.
Using Hofstede’s measures of national culture, Husted (1999) identifies power distance,
uncertainty avoidance and masculinity to have significant impact on national corruption. Kimbro (2002)
reports power distance and individualism as related to corruption after controlling for legal and
monitoring variables the way we do. It appears that the consensus is that individualism and power
distance are the cultural traits that are associated with corruption; collectivistic cultures and cultures with
high power distance gravitate towards high prevalence of corruption. If FDI has the catalyst role through
the three effects, it would moderate the harmful effects of culture on corruption.
15
Columns (I) through (IV) of Table 4 examine the interaction between power distance and FDI.
The results show that, consistent with previous research (see, for examples, Husted (1999), Triandis et al.
(2001)), high power-distance countries tend to have high prevalence of corruption. More significantly, the
effect of high power-distance on corruption is significantly lower in the presence of FDI; the interaction
terms between FDI and power-distance are robustly negative and statistically significant at the one per
cent level. Columns (V) through (VIII) provide similar results on the interaction of
individualism/collectivism and FDI. Though the coefficient is positive, individualism has no discernible
direct effect on incidence of corruption. This is consistent with existing, though ambiguous, evidence
about individualism in the literature. For example, Husted (1999) finds no direct effect from
individualism to corruption, while Kimbro (2002) finds direct effects, once the effect of countries’ wealth
is controlled for. More importantly, the effects of individualism/collectivism on corruption are
significantly lower in the presence of FDI.6
Our analysis in the previous section reveals that one of the critical variables that explain the
variations in the prevalence of corruption is education. It can be argued that, via the professionalization
effect, FDI presence complements education in transforming the institutional environment of countries.
Columns (IX) through (XI) report the results. For education we use the average yearly secondary school
enrollment, averaged over 1970 though 2000.7 The use of decade averages over 1970s, 1980s and 1990s
does not change the results. Consistent with our earlier results, education has positive, though moderate,
direct effects on corruption. The coefficients on the education variable are negative and significant at ten
per cent level. Consistent with our conjecture, the positive effects of education on corruption are
significantly larger in the presence of FDI; the interaction terms between education and FDI are robustly
negative and statistically significant as one per cent level. The models in Table 4 perform well, explaining 6 For reasons outlined earlier, we focus on the power distance and individualism attributes of national culture.
Though not reported for brevity, the results using the other two attributes, masculinity and uncertainty avoidance, provide qualitatively similar evidence. Again for brevity, we use the overall average FDI over the entire period of 1970 through 1997 as the FDI variable. However, the results are robust when we use the decade averages instead.
7 Secondary school enrollment is a standard measure of human capital in the literature of economic growth (e.g. Barro (1991)).
16
more than 80 percent of the cross-country variations in corruption, though our sample has significantly
shrunk because of missing values.
Robustness tests Using alternative measures for the independent variable We provide additional sensitivity checks in this section. First, instead of using the actual values
of FDI as independent variable, we include group indicator of high or low FDI countries in the regression.
We group the countries into three categories based on their rankings of FDI flows, and designate the
bottom-third countries as low-FDI countries with a dummy variable value of 0, and the top-third
countries as high-FDI countries with a dummy variable value of 1. Columns (I) through (IV) of Table 5
show that our main findings are robust to the alternative measure of FDI. For brevity, we report the
results using the FDI and Education variables generated based on averages over the period 1970 through
1997. The results are similar if we use values based on decade averages in 1970s, 1980s or 1990s.
Instrumental variables methodology
Our findings are based on regressing corruption in 2000s on lagged values of FDI, the lagged
values going as far back as 30 years. The fact that the FDI values are not contemporaneous with the
corruption data minimizes the concerns one may have about the possibility of reverse causality.
However, it could still be argued that past FDI is made based on predictions about the institutional
environment in the future such that a forecast of low corruption in the future attracts more FDI today. The
robust findings on the channels through which past FDI moderates the harmful effects of culture and
strengthens the beneficial effects of education, shown in the previous section, go a long way in allaying
our concerns on reverse causality.
An alternative approach to address the endogeneity issue would be to use instruments that
disentangle the link between FDI and corruption. We estimate the basic models using the instrumental
variables methodology, where we attempt to relate the exogenous component of FDI to corruption. The
ideal instruments are variables that might affect corruption but less likely to be affected by it. The most
17
difficult task in this setting, however, is the identification of appropriate instruments. It is customary in
the finance and economics literature to use such institutional variables as legal origin or colonial history.
These variables however, are not useful for our case, as both corruption and FDI are driven by the
institutional environment. We look for variables that explain FDI but less likely to be related with
corruption. The literature provides a menu of FDI determinants, but most variables are institutional. In
addition to variables related to the host country investment climate, FDI is facilitated by better
infrastructure including communication networks and supply of power. We use two variables of this
nature as instruments: (a) per capita electricity power consumption, and (b) telephone lines (per 1,000
people). We examine the effects of the exogenous component of FDI (the component explainable by our
instruments) on corruption. Columns (V) through (VIII) of Table 5 present the instrumental variables
(IV) results. Column (V) confirm the major findings from Table 4 that corruption is lower in countries
with high past FDI predicted by the instruments. Columns (VI) through (VIII) confirm the main results
that FDI moderates the harmful effects of culture and strengthens the positive effects of education.8
Change in corruption as a dependent variable
To address the concern on causality further, we also examine the relation between past FDI and
changes (rather than levels) in the corruption measures. Based on the data, we compute the difference
between the average corruption level over 2000 through 2004 and the average corruption index between
1995 and 1999, and examine whether the change in the index levels is related to past FDI flows as
hypothesized. The results, shown in Table 6, confirm the main results so far. The change in corruption is
inversely related to past FDI. In addition, FDI appears to moderate the harmful effects of culture and
8 We follow a two-step procedure where we predict the level of FDI using our two instruments in the first step,
and use the predicted FDI values and other predetermined variables to explain variations in corruption. The test for the validity of the instruments using GMM estimation does not support the hypothesis. However, in this test, the set of instruments include both the two instrumental variables we specified and the six exogenous explanatory variables in the model; since, with only two instruments, the model will be under-identified. Nevertheless, this result reflects the difficulty of finding good instruments in our context and suggests that the readers should interpret our instrumental variables results with this limitation in mind.
18
strengthens the positive effects of education, as the interaction terms between past FDI and our proxies of
culture and education are significantly negative.9
VI. Summary and conclusions
Most empirical research so far examines how the institutional environment of corruption shapes
the behavior of MNCs. In this study, we highlight the other side of the picture: how the presence of MNC
may shape the institutional environment of corruption over time. We recognize that, in order to strive for
external legitimacy, the MNC needs to adapt to its institutional context. Most FDI represents flows from
developed countries, where there is generally less corruption. The behavior of MNC in host country is
constrained by the regulatory pressure from home country and the international business community (e.g.
U.S. Foreign Corrupt Practices Act and OECD Convention on Combating Bribery of Foreign Public
Officials in International Business Transactions). In dealing with a foreign business party, the local
government officials are constrained somewhat in their bribery acts; it cannot be just business as usual.
Over time, together with the demonstration and the professionalization effects, local government officials
and business people may model themselves after the MNCs and modify their traditional business
practices. They may want to enhance legitimacy within the global business community, raise the
country’s international reputation, and attract more business into their country.
We empirically examine our propositions based on an extensive data on FDI and corruption
around the world, for a large sample of countries, over the last 30 years. First, consistent with our thesis,
we find that current corruption level is significantly lower in countries with high FDI flows in the past.
This is true whether we use FDI in 1970s, 1980s or 1990s. Second, we find strong evidence that the
harmful effects of culture on corruption are lower and the beneficial effects of education on corruption are
higher in countries with higher FDI in the past. Our results are robust to omitted variables bias as we 9 In this study, we do not use the change of corruption level as our main dependent variable. Transparency
International computes the Corruption Perception Index as a composite of a number of independent surveys. As explained in Robertson and Watson (2004, p. 390), the sources used differ from year to year. Hence, the CPI is suitable for cross-sectional comparisons but unsuitable for longitudinal comparisons. To alleviate the concern of varying sources over time, we use the average corruption levels of two broad periods to compute the difference. Nevertheless, the readers should interpret the findings with such limitation in mind.
19
control for a host of host-country characteristics, including the level of economic development, political
tradition, education, culture, legal system, religious orientation and institutional development.
We use multiple ways to alleviate the potential concerns of reverse causality. Firstly, we regress
corruption in 2000s on lagged values of FDI, the lagged values going as far back as 30 years. Secondly,
we explore the interaction effects between FDI and variables such as culture and education. Thirdly, we
employ the instrumental variables methodology, using two instrumental variables, communication
network and supply of power, to relate the exogenous component of FDI to corruption. Fourthly, we
regress changes (rather than levels) in the corruption measures on past FDI. The robust results give us
confidence that there is a causal effect flowing from FDI to corruption.
Our findings confirm the fruitfulness of studying the potential impact of MNCs on the
organizational patterns within a country. As contended by Westney (1993), MNC subsidiaries in some
countries can play a major role in establishing building blocks of organizations. The introduction of new
modes of business practice in MNC subsidiaries can challenge the legitimacy of existing patterns and
stimulate debates on better business practices, initiating a “de-institutionalization” process.
Certainly, it would be naïve to think that the influence of MNCs on its institutional environment
is always good. There are plenty of anecdotal evidences that MNCs sometimes bring in undesirable
influences. However, in the area of corruption, our empirical findings show that the average effect is
positive: the presence of FDI could help reduce the corruption level of a host country over time. It enables
the MNC to point out to the host government and its people another potential benefit of opening its doors
to foreign direct investment. Such a dynamic perspective provides a glimmer of hope to host countries
where corruption is widely prevalent.
20
References
Ades, A. and Di Tella, R. (1994) ‘Competition and Corruption’, Institute of Economics and Statistics Discussion Paper 169, University of Oxford.
Aitken, B. J. and Harrison, A.E. (1999) ‘Do Domestic Firms Benefit from Direct Foreign Investment? Evidence from Venezuela’, American Economic Review 89: 605-18.
Barro, R. (1991) ‘Economic Growth in A Cross-Section of Countries’, Quarterly Journal of Economics CVI: 407–444.
———. (1996) Determinants of Economic Growth: A Cross Country Empirical Study, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER working paper 5698.
Blomstrom, M. and Kokko, A. (1998) ‘Multinational Corporations and Spillovers’, Journal of Economic Surveys 12: 247-77.
Dacin, T., Ventresca, M. and Beal, B. (1999) ‘The Embeddedness of Organizations: Dialogue & Directions’, Journal of Management 25: 317-356.
Davis, P. S., Desai, A. B. and Francis, J. D. (2000) ‘ Mode of International Entry: An Isomorphism Perspective’, Journal of International Business Studies 31(2): 239–258.
Djankov, S. D., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. (2003) ‘Courts’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, 453-517.
DiMaggio, P. and Powell, W. (1983) ‘The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields’, American Sociological Review 48 (2): 147-160.
Doh, J., Rodriguez, P., Uhlenbruck, K., Collins, J. and Eden, L. (2003) ‘Coping with Corruption in Foreign Markets’, Academy of Management Executive 17 (3): 114-127.
Eden, L., Levitas, E. and Martinez, R. (1997) ‘The Production, Transfer, and Spillover Technology’, Small Business Economics 9 (1), February: 53-66.
Globerman, S. (1979) ‘Foreign Direct Investment and ‘Spillover’ Efficiency Benefits in Canadian Manufacturing Industries’, Canadian Journal of Economics 12: 42-56.
Glynn, M. A. and Abzug, R. (2002) ‘Institutional Identity: Symbolic Isomorphism and Organizational Names’, Academy of Management Journal 45: 267–280.
Görg, H. and Strobl, E. (2001) ‘Multinational Companies and Productivity Spillovers: A Meta-Analysis’, The Economic Journal 111: 723-39.
21
Haddad, M. and Harrison, A. (1993) ‘Are There Positive Spillovers from Direct Foreign Investment?: Evidence from Panel Data for Morocco’, Journal of Development Economics 42: 51-74.
Henisz, W. J., (2000) ‘The Institutional Environment of Economic Growth,’ Economics and Politics, 12,
1-31.
Hofstede, G. (2001) Culture’s Consequences, 2nd Edition, London: Sage Publications.
Husted B. (1999) ‘Wealth, Culture and Corruption’, Journal of International Business Studies 30 (2): 339-360.
Jaggers, K., Marshall, M.G., (2000) ‘Polity IV Project,’ Working Paper, Center for International
Development and Conflict Management, University of Maryland.
Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., and Zoido_Lobatón, P. (1999) ‘Governance Matters’, World Bank Research Paper No. 2196.
Kimbro, M. (2002) ‘A Cross-Country Empirical Investigation of Corruption and Its Relationship to Economic, Cultural, and Monitoring Institutions: An Examination of the Role of Accounting and Financial Statements Quality’, Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance 17:325-351.
Knack, S. and Keefer, P. (1995) ‘Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures’, Economics and Politics 7 (no. 3): 207–27.
Knack, S. and Keefer, P. (1997) ‘Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff, a Cross-Country Investigation’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 112:1251–1288.
Kostova, T. and Roth, K. (2002) ‘Adoption of an Organizational Practice by Subsidiaries of Multinational Corporations: Institutional and Relational Effects’, Academy of Management Journal 45: 215–233.
Lambsdorff, J. (1999) ‘Corruption in Empirical Research: A Review’, Transparency International Working Paper, Berlin, Germany.
La Porta, R.F., Lo´pez de Silanes, Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (1997) ‘Trust in Large Organizations’, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings LXXXVII (May): 333–38.
Liu, X., Siler, P., Wang, C. and Wei, Y. (2000) ‘Productivity Spillovers from Foreign Direct Investment: Evidence from UK Industry Level Panel Data’, Journal of International Business Studies 31: 407-25.
Macrae, John. (1982) ‘Underdevelopment and the Economics of Corruption: A Game Theory Approach’, World Development 10 (8): 677-87.
Mauro, P. (1995) ‘Corruption and Growth’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 110: 681–712.
22
Mauro, P. (1997) ‘The Effects of Corruption on Growth Investment, and Government Expenditure: A Cross-Country Analysis’, in K. A. Elliott (ed) Corruption and the Global Economy.
Oliver, C. (1997) ‘Sustainable Competitive Advantage: Combining Institutional and Resource-Based Views’, Strategic Management Journal 18 (9): 697-713.
Ramirez, A. and Kwok, C. (2006) ‘Multinationality as a Moderator of National Institutions: The Case of Culture and Capital Structure Decisions,’ CIBER Working Paper, University of South Carolina.
Rao, A. N., Pearce, J. L., Xin, K. (2005) ‘Governments, Reciprocal Exchange and Trust among Business Associates,’ Journal of International Business Studies 36, 104-118.
Robertson, C. J., and Watson, A. (2004) ‘Corruption and Change: The Impact of Foreign Direct Investment’, Strategic Management Journal 25: 385-396.
Rodriguez, P., Uhlenbruck, K. and Eden, L. (2005) ‘Government Corruption and the Entry Strategies of Multinationals’, Academy of Management Review 30:383-396.
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1975) ‘The Economics of Corruption’, Journal of Public Economics IV:187–203.
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1999) Corruption and Government: Causes, Consequences, and Reform, London: Cambridge University Press.
Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (1993) ‘Corruption’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 108: 599–617.
Triandis, H.C., Carnevale P., Gelfand, M., Robert C., Wasti, A., Probst, T., Kashima, E., Dragonas, T., Chan, D., Chen, X., Kim, U., Drue, C., Vliert, E., Iwao, S., Ohibuchi, K., Schmitz, P. (2001) ‘Culture and Deception in Negotiations: A Multilevel Analysis’, International Journal of Cross Cultural Management 1, 73-90.
Transparency International (2001) Corruption Perceptions Index 2001, Berlin: Transparency International.
Wei, S.1997. Why is Corruption So Much More Taxing Than Tax? Arbitrariness kills, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER working paper 6255.
Westney, D.E. (1993) ‘Institutionalization Theory and the Multinational Corporation’, in S. Ghoshal and D.E. Westney (Eds) Organization Theory and the Multinational Corporation: 53–75, New York: St. Martin’s Press.
World Bank (2000) World Development Report: Attacking Poverty, New York: Oxford University Press. World Bank (1999) World Development Indicators. World Bank: Washington DC.
23
Figure 1: MNC as an Agent of Change for Host-Country Institutions
MNC
Host Country Government and Business Community
International Business Community
Home Country Environment
Host Country Environment
Global Business Environment
• Regulatory Pressure Effect • Demonstration Effect • Professionalization Effect
24
Table 1: Summary Statistics
Variable Mean Std Dev Minimum Maximum N
Dependent Variables: Corruption 2000-04
5.634
2.313
0.220
8.900
120
Independent Variables: FDI to GDP in 1970s FDI to GDP in 1980s FDI to GDP in 1990s FDI to GDP 1970-1997
0.933 1.089 2.128 1.488
1.318 2.089 4.057 2.204
-1.844 -4.206 -11.028 -4.365
5.838 14.838 37.284 14.191
113 136 140 142
Control Variables: Per Capita GDP
8.291
1.123
6.064
10.164
133
Education in 1970s 36.846 27.741 1.000 94.667 128 Education in 1980s 47.376 30.237 3.460 107.679 131 Education in 1990s 55.001 33.795 5.257 129.966 130 Education in 1970-1997 44.408 29.482 1.171 104.442 143 Democracy 5.051 3.775 0 10.000 85 Political Constraint 0.348 0.324 0 0.893 133 Rule of Law 6.907 2.445 1.670 10.000 76
Legal Formalism 3.549 1.015 1.414 5.907 94
Culture
Power Distance
56.41
21.48
11.00
104.00
56
Individualism/Collectivism 43.50 25.20 6.00 91.00 56
Instrumental Variables:
Telephone Lines
85.85
123.44
0.65
594.81
134 Electricity Consumption
(kwh per capita) 7.2E10 2.8E11 2.6E7 2.7E12 104
25
Table 2: Correlation Matrix (figures in parentheses are p values) Corruption Per capita
GDP FDI in 1970s
FDI in 1980s
FDI in 1990s
FDI 1970-1997
Education in 1970s
Education in 1980s
Education in 1990s
Education in 1970-
1997
Power
Distance
Individualism Collectivism
Democracy Political Constraint
Per Capita GDP -0.835 (0.0001)
FDI in 1970s -0.1154 (0.141)
0.125 (0.207)
FDI in 1980s -0.285 (0.003)
0.208 (0.022)
0.464 (<.0001)
FDI in 1990s -0.174 (0.076)
0.109 (0.223)
0.078 (0.409)
0.419 (<.0001)
FDI in 1970-1997 -0.208 (0.032)
0.119 (0.180)
0.405 (<.0001)
0.761 (<.0001)
0.867 (<.0001)
Education in 1970s -0.771 (0.0001)
0.889 (<.0001)
0.086 (0.386)
0.088 (0.343)
0.019 (0.839)
0.022 (0.817)
Education in 1980s -0.745 (0.0001)
0.834 (<.0001)
0.775 (<.0001)
0.054 (0.557)
0.108 (0.233)
0.069 (0.439)
0.954 (<.0001)
Education in in 1990s -0.799 (0.0001)
0.881 (<.0001)
0.089 (0.371)
0.087 (0.347)
0.079 (0.388)
0.027 (0.766)
0.923 (<.0001)
0.951 (<.0001)
Education in 1970-1997
-0.746 (0.0001)
0.824 (<.0001)
0.120 (0.208)
0.091 (0.303)
-0.026 (0.762)
-0.019 (0.818)
0.964 (<.0001)
0.989 (<.0001)
0.975 (<.0001)
Power Distance 0.682 (<.0001)
-0.616 (<.0001)
-0.002 (0.984)
-0.018 (0.904)
-0.043 (0.765)
-0.004 (0.977)
-0.594 (<.0001)
-0.618 (<.0001)
-0.627 (<.0001)
-0.591 (<.0001)
Individualism/Collectivism
-0.702 (<.0001)
0.742 (<.0001)
-0.122 (0.418)
-0.030 (0.833)
-0.151 (0.295)
-0.136 (0.344)
0.686 (<.0001)
0.666 (<.0001)
0.749 (<.0001)
0.669 (<.0001)
-0.647 (<.0001)
Democracy -0.686 (<.0001)
0.689 (<.0001)
0.104 (0.366)
0.061 (0.585)
0.071 (0.528)
0.091 (0.413)
0.709 (<.0001)
0.673 (<.0001)
0.737 (<.0001)
0.704 (<.0001)
-0.688 (<.0001)
0.721 (<.0001)
Political Constraint -0.607 (<.0001)
0.579 (<.0001)
0.103 (0.315)
0.075 (0.429)
-0.026 (0.776)
-0.018 (0.840)
0.648 (<.0001)
0.596 (<.0001)
0.611 (<.0001)
0.610 (<.0001)
-0.449 (<.0001)
0.533 (<.0001)
0.825 (<.0001)
Rule of Law -0.801 (<.0001)
0.703 (<.0001)
0.050 (0.694)
0.175 (0.151)
0.074 (0.542)
0.120 (0.322)
0.632 (<.0001)
0.571 (<.0001)
0.608 (<.0001)
0.583 (<.0001)
-0.645 (<.0001)
0.693 (<.0001)
0.524 (<.0001)
0.420 (<.0001)
26
Table 3: FDI and Corruption
I II III IV V VI VII VIII IX X XI XII XIII XIV XV
FDI
FDI in 1970s -0.191b
(0.095) -0.169c
(0.092) -0.186
(0.117)
FDI in 1980s -0.289a
(0.088) -0.313a
(0.086) -0.359a
(0.092) -0.322a
(0.092)
FDI in 1990s -0.206a
(0.066) -0.197a
(0.064) -0.198b
(0.019) -0.162b
(0.076)
FDI in 70-1997 -0.281a
(0.088) -0.269a
(0.085) -0.327a
(0.103) -0.263b
(0.102) Education Education in 1970s -0.016b
(0.008) -0.0.13
(0.011)
Education in 1980s -0.013b
(0.006) -0.014c
(0.008) -0.023b
(0.009)
Education in 1990s -0.016b
(0.006) -0.019b
(0.008) -0.025a
(0.008)
Education in 70- 1997
-0.015a (0.006)
-0.016b
(0.008) -0.019b
(0.008) Political Tradition Democracy -0.091
(0.071) -0.149b
(0.063) -0.107 (0.065)
-0.117c
(0.064) -0.066 (0.051)
-0.003 (0.054)
-0.035 (0.050)
Political Constraint 0.798 (0.759)
0.619 (0.703)
0.788 (0.718)
0.719 (0.708)
0.305 (0.777)
0.426 (0.779)
0.341 (0.786)
Legal Environment
Rule of Law -0.281a
(0.094) -0.273a
(0.088) -0.276a
(0.089) Legal Formalism 0.285b
(0.094) 0.323b
(0.133) 0.302b
(0.137) GDP per Capita -0.0004a
(2E-5) -0.0004a
(2E-4) -0.0004a
(2E-4) -0.0004a
(2E-4) -0.0004a
(5E-5) -0.0004a
(4E-5) -0.0003a
(4E-5) -0.0004a
(3E-5) -0.0004a
(6E-5) -0.0003a
(5E-5) -0.0003a
(5E-5) -0.0001a
(4E-5) -0.0001b
(7E-5) -0.0001b
(7E-5) -0.0002a
(6E-5)
Adjusted R-Square 0.78 0.79 0.79 0.79 0.80 0.81 0.82 0.81 0.80 0.83 0.82 0.82 0.86 0.85 0.84 Sample 87 96 100 100 84 92 95 99 66 68 69 71 56 57 59
a Significant at 1 per cent; b significant at 5 per cent; c significant at 10 per cent. The figures in parentheses are standard errors.
27
Table 4: FDI and Corruption – Channels of Influence I II III IV V VI VII VIII IX X XI
Culture Power Distance
0.040a
(0.009)
0.035a
(0.010)
0.036a
(0.011)
0.026b
(0.012)
Individualism/Collectivism 0.000 (0.009)
0.005 (0.009)
0.011 (0.012)
0.017 (0.012)
Education Education in 70-1997
-0.021b
(0.009)
-0.024b
(0.010)
-0.023b
(0.010)
-0.0221b
(0.008
-0.023b
(0.010)
-0.024b
(0.010)
-0.009 (0.006)
-0.021c
(0.010)
0.021c
(0.010) FDI X Power Distance Interactions
FDI in 1970-1997 X Power Distance
-0.006a
(0.002) -0.006a
(0.001) -0.006a
(0.002) -0.004b
(0.001)
FDI X Individualism/Collectivism Interaction
FDI in 70-1997 X Individualism/Collectivism
-0.014a
(0.003) -0.013a
(0.003) -0.015a
(0.003) -0.010b
(0.004)
FDI X Education Interaction FDI in 70-1997 X Education
in70-1997
-0.006a
(0.002)
-0.007a
(0.002)
-0.004b
(0.002)
Political Tradition Democracy
0.011 (0.091)
0.088 (0.102)
-0.033 (0.091)
0.0311 (0.094)
-0.066 (0.085)
0.040 (0.099)
Political Constraint -0.216 (0.948)
-0.175 (0.970)
-0.483 (0.979)
-0.194 (0.980)
-0.305 (0.996)
-0.128 (1.005)
Legal Environment Rule of Law
-0.195 (0.119)
-0.238b
(0.116)
-0.238c
(0.121) Legal Formalism 0.276
(0.189) 0.325
(0.213) 0.327
(0.198) GDP per Capita -0.0003a
(4E-5) -0.0003a
(5E-5) -0.0003a
(5E-5) -0.0002a
(7E-5) -0.0004a
(5E-5) -0.0003a
(5E-5) -0.0003a
(6E-5) -0.0003a
(7E-4) -0.0003a
(3E-5) -0.0003a
(6E-5) -0.0002a
(7E-5)
Adjusted R-Square 0.83 0.85 0.83 0.84 0.83 0.84 0.82 0.84 0.83 0.81 0.83 Sample 48 48 42 42 48 48 42 42 99 42 42
a Significant at 1 per cent; b significant at 5 per cent; c significant at 10 per cent. The figures in parentheses are standard errors.
28
Table 5: Robustness Tests
FDI as a dummy Variable Instrumental Variables I II III IV V
VI VII VIII
FDI in 1970-1997 -0.535b
(0.182) -1.221a
(0.342)
Culture Power Distance
0.026b
(0.012)
0.025b
(0.012)
Individualism/Collectivism 0.027 b (0.013)
0.026b
(0.012)
Education in 70-1997 -0.015c
(0.008) -0.014
(0.010) -0.022b
(0.010) -0.013
(0.011) -0.016b
(0.008) -0.017
(0.010) -0.023b
(0.010) -0.006 (0.011)
FDIXPD Interaction
FDI in 1970-1997 X Power Distance
-0.011b
(0.004) -0.013
(0.008)
FDI X IC Interaction
FDI in 70-1997XIC -0.010b
(0.004)
-0.014b
(0.005)
FDI X Education FDI in 70-1997 X Education in 70-1997
-0.007b
(0.003)
-0.010b
(0.004)
Political Tradition Democracy
-0.058 (0.072)
0.066
(0.099)
0.041
(0.093)
0.068
(0.093)
0.023
(0.071)
0.161
(0.100)
0.107
(0.093)
0.121
(0.091) Political Constraint 0.533
(0.775) 0.386
(0.939) 0.121
(0.956) 0.112
(0.980) 0.266
(0.735) 0.030
(0.994) -0.016 (0.946)
-0.047 (0.969)
Legal Environment Rule of Law
-0.256a
(0.088)
-0.258b
(0.111)
-0.273b
(0.112)
-0.251b
(0.116)
-0.237a
(0.086)
-0.249b
(0.119)
-0.270b
(0.110)
-0.262b
(0.113) Legal Formalism 0.316b
(0.133) 0.307
(0.174) 0.458b
(0.185) 0.362c
(0.182) 0.382a
(0.129) 0.429b
(0.174) 0.564a
(0.176) 0.467a
(0.168) GDP per Capita -0.0002a
(6E-5) 0.0002a
(7E-5) 0.0003a
(7E-5) 0.0002a
(7E-5) -0.00008
(6E-5) -0.0002b
(8E-5) -0.0002a
(7E-5) -0.0002a
(7E-5) Adjusted R-Square 0.85 0.84 0.85 0.84 0.85 0.83 0.84 0.83 Sample 59 42 42 42 57 42 42 42
a Significant at 1 per cent; b significant at 5 per cent; c significant at 10 per cent. The figures in parentheses are standard errors.
29
Table 6: FDI and Change of Corruption
Corruption as a Change I II III IV
FDI in 1970-1997 -0.595a
(0.221)
Culture Power Distance
0.064b
(0.024)
Individualism/Collectivism 0.051 c (0.026)
Education in 70-1997 -0.043a
(0.017) -0.047b
(0.019) -0.054b
(0.021) -0.040 c
(0.021) FDIXPD Interaction
FDI in 1970-1997 X Power Distance
-0.010a
(0.004)
FDI X IC Interaction
FDI in 70-1997XIC -0.020b
(0.0086)
FDI X Education FDI in 70-1997 X Education
in 70-1997
-0.011b
(0.005)
Political Tradition Democracy
-0.090 (0.152)
0.174
(0.198)
0.025
(0.186)
0.034
(0.193) Political Constraint 0.714
(1.709) -1.703 (2.127)
-1.115 (2.121)
-1.516 (2.230)
Legal Environment Rule of Law
-0.631a
(0.175)
-0.401c
(0.231)
-0.549b
(0.227)
-0.485b
(0.237) Legal Formalism 0.667b
(0.289) 0.715 c (0.387)
0.906c
(0.481) 0.733c
(0.409)
GDP per Capita -0.0003a
(1E-4) 0.0004a
(1E-4) 0.0005a
(1E-4) 0.0004a
(1E-4)
Adjusted R-Square 0.86 0.86 0.85 0.84
Sample 54 40 40 40
a Significant at 1 per cent; b significant at 5 per cent; c significant at 10 per cent. The figures in parentheses are standard errors.
30
Appendix 1: Variables and Sources Variables Definition Sources Dependent Variables: Corruption
A measure of the corruption perception. Corruption is defined as abuse of public office, and the corruption index measures the corruption perception based on survey of business people and analysts. The measure is rescaled from the original by taking the difference from 10. The values are averages over the period 2000 through 2004
Source: Transparency International (various issues)
Independent Variable: FDI to GDP ratio (%) in 70s, 80s, 90s and 1970-1997
Foreign direct investment is inflows of investment to acquire a lasting management interest (10 percent or more of voting stock) in an enterprise operating in an economy other than that of the investor. It is the sum of equity capital, reinvestment of earnings, other long-term capital, and short-term capital as shown in the balance of payments. The values are decade averages over 1970s, 1980s, 1990s and over the period 1970 through 1997.
Source: World Bank (1999)
Education (in 70s, 80s, 90s, and 1970-1997)
Gross secondary enrollment ratio is the ratio of total enrollment, regardless of age, to the population of the age group that officially corresponds to the level of education shown. It is measured as secondary school enrollment at a fraction of the age group eligible to the level of education. The values are decade averages over the 1970s, the 1980s, the 1990s and overall average over the period 1970 through 1997.
Source: World Bank (1999)
Culture Power Distance Individualism/Collectivism
Hofstede’s cultural value that reflects the response of people to inequality. It represents the extent to which the less powerful members of society accept, expect or prefer injustice.
Hofstede’s cultural value that reflects the degree to which people in society are primarily concerned with their own self-interest over that of the collective.
Source: Hofstede (2001) Source: Hofstede (2001)
Control Variables Per capita GDP
The logarithm of average per capita GDP
Source: World Bank (1999)
Democracy Political Constraints
A measure of the degree of democracy in a given country based on: (1) the competitiveness of political participation; (2) the openness and competitiveness of executive recruitment; and (3) the constraints on the chief executive. The variable ranges from zero to ten, where higher values equal a higher degree of institutionalized democracy. This variable is calculated as the average from 1960 through 2000, or for specific years as needed in the tables. A measure of the extent of institutionalized constraints on the decision making of political actors. The values are averages over 1970 through 2000
Source: Jaggers and Marshall (2000). Source: Henisz (2000)
Rule of Law Legal Formalism
A measure of the prevalence of law and order and is based on the Political Risk Services Group’s International Country Guide (various issues), on a scale of 0 to 10. The index measures substantive and procedural statutory intervention in judicial cases at lower-level civil trial courts, and is formed by adding up the following indices: (i) professionals vs. laymen, (ii) written vs. oral elements, (iii) legal justification, (iv) statutory regulation of evidence, (v) control of superior review, (vi) engagement formalities, and (vii) independent procedural actions. The index ranges from 0 to 7, where 7 means a higher level of control or intervention in the judicial process.
Source: Djankov et al. (2003) Source: Djankov et al. (2003)
Instrumental Variables Telephone Lines Electricity Consumption
Telephone lines are the total number of fixed lines and mobile phone subscribers (per 1,000 people). Fixed lines are telephone mainlines connecting a customer's equipment to the public switched telephone network. Mobile phone subscribers refer to users of portable telephones subscribing to an automatic public mobile telephone service using cellular technology that provides access to the public switched telephone network. The values are averages over 1970 through 1997.
Electric power consumption measures the production of power plants and combined heat and power plants, less distribution losses, and own use by heat and power plants per capita. The value is average over 1970 through 1997.
Source: World Bank (1999) Source: World Bank (1999)
DAVIDSON INSTITUTE WORKING PAPER SERIES – Most Recent Papers The entire Working Paper Series may be downloaded free of charge at: www.wdi.umich.edu
CURRENT AS OF 07/6/07 Publication Authors Date No. 882: The MNC as an Agent of Change for Host-Country Institutions: FDI & Corruption
Chuck Kwok and Solomon Tadesse
Sept 2006
No. 881: The Allocation and Monitoring Role of Capital Markets: Theory and International Evidence
Solomon Tadesse March 2003
No. 880: Tunisia: Sources of Real Exchange Rate Fluctuations Sfia Mohamed Daly
March 2006
No. 879: Financial Development & Technology Solomon Tadesse June 2007
No. 878: Consolidation, Scale Economics & Technological Change in Japanese Banking
Solomon Tadesse Feb 2005
No. 877: Innovation, Information and Financial Architecture Solomon Tadesse June 2007
No. 876: Corporate Cash Holdings, National Culture, and Multinationality
Andres Ramirez and Solomon Tadesse
June 2007
No. 875: The Economic Value of Regulated Disclosure: Evidence from the Banking Sector
Solomon Tadesse Jan 2006
No. 874:Banking Fragility & Disclosure: International Evidence Solomon Tadesse Sept 2006
No. 873: The Impact of Outward FDI on Home-Country Employment in a Low-Cost Transition Economy
Jaan Masso, Urmas Varblane and Priit Vahter
May 2007
No. 872: Local Distributional Effects of Government Cash Transfers in Chile
Claudio A. Agostini and Philip Brown
May 2007
No. 871: How do Workers Fare During Transition?Perceptions of Job Insecurity among Russian Workers, 1995-2004
Susan J. Linz and Anastasia Semykina
April 2007
No. 870: Does Reform Work? An Econometric Examination of the Reform-Growth Puzzle
Ian Babetskii and Nauro Campos April 2007
No. 869: Perceptions and Behavior: Analyzing Wage Arrears in Russia Susan Linz, Anastasia Semykina and Charles Petrin
June 2006
No. 868: The Endogeneity of Association Agreements and their Impact on Trade for Eastern Countries: Empirical Evidence for Romania
Christophe Rault, Ana Maria Sova and Robert Sova
April 2007
No. 867: Institutions & Entrepreneurship Development in Russia: A Comparative Perspective
Saul Estrin, Ruta Aidis and Tomasz Mickiewicz
Feb 2007
No. 866: Dutch Disease Scare in Kazakhstan: Is it real? Balázs Égert and Carol S. Leonard March 2007
No. 865: Minimum Wage and Tax Evasion: Theory and Evidence
Mirco Tonin Jan 2007
No. 864: Dynamics of the Financial Wealth of the Institutional Sectors in Bulgaria: Empirical Studies of the Post-Communist Period
Nikolay Nenovsky and Gergana Mihaylova
March 2007
No. 863: Impact of Derivatives Trading on Emerging Capital Markets: A Note on Expiration Day Effects in India
Sumon Kumar Bhaumik and Suchismita Bose
March 2007
No. 862: Short- & Medium- Term Determinants of Current Account Balances in Middle East & North Africa Countries
Aleksander Aristovnik March 2007
No. 861: Time-Varying Comovements in Developed and Emerging European Stock Markets: Evidence from Intraday Data
Balázs Égert and Evžen Kočenda March 2007
No: 860: Giving Children a Better Start: Preschool Attendance & School-Age Profiles
Sam Berlinski, Sebastian Galiani and Marco Manacorda
Jan 2007
No. 859: Real Exchange Rates in Small open OECD & Transition Economies: Comparing Apples with Oranges?
Balázs Égert, Kirsten Lommatzsch and Amina Lahreche-Revil
Jan 2007
No. 858: Is Education the Panacea for Economic Deprivation of Muslims? Evidence from Wage Earners in India, 1987-2004
Sumon Kumar Bhaumik and Manisha Chakrabarty
Jan 2007
No. 857: Human Capital, Economic Growth, and Regional Inequality in China
Belton Fleisher, Haizheng Li and Min Qiang Zhao
Jan 2007